{ "id": "RL34115", "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORTS", "number": "RL34115", "active": true, "source": "EveryCRSReport.com, University of North Texas Libraries Government Documents Department", "versions": [ { "source": "EveryCRSReport.com", "id": 586207, "date": "2017-08-01", "retrieved": "2020-01-02T14:15:56.906947", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": "A striking feature of the modern U.S. economy is its growing openness\u2014its increased integration with the rest of the world. The attention of tax policymakers has recently been focused on the growing participation of U.S. firms in the international economy and the increased pressure that engagement places on the U.S. system for taxing overseas business. Is the current U.S. system for taxing U.S. international business the appropriate one for the modern era of globalized business operations, or should its basic structure be reformed?\nThe current U.S. system for taxing international business is a hybrid. In part, the system is based on a residence principle, applying U.S. taxes on a worldwide basis to U.S. firms while granting foreign tax credits to alleviate double taxation. The system, however, also permits U.S. firms to defer foreign-source income indefinitely\u2014a feature that approaches a territorial tax jurisdiction. In keeping with its mixed structure, the system produces a patchwork of economic effects that depend on the location of foreign investment and the circumstances of the firm. Broadly, the system poses a tax incentive to invest in countries with low tax rates of their own and a disincentive to invest in high-tax countries. In theory, U.S. investment should be skewed toward low-tax countries and away from high-tax locations.\nEvaluations of the current tax system vary, and so do prescriptions for reform. According to traditional economic analysis, world economic welfare is maximized by a system that applies the same tax burden to prospective (marginal) foreign and domestic investment so that taxes do not distort investment decisions. Such a system possesses capital export neutrality, and could be accomplished by worldwide taxation applied to all foreign operations along with an unlimited foreign tax credit. In contrast, a system that maximizes national welfare\u2014a system possessing national neutrality\u2014would impose a higher tax burden on foreign investment, thus permitting an overall disincentive for foreign investment. Such a system would impose worldwide taxation but would permit only a deduction, and not a credit, for foreign taxes.\nA tax system based on territorial taxation would exempt overseas business investment from U.S. tax. In recent years, several proponents of territorial taxation have argued that changes in the world economy have rendered traditional prescriptions for international taxation obsolete and instead prescribe territorial taxation as a means of maximizing both world and national economic welfare. For such a system to be neutral, however, capital would have to be completely immobile across locations. A case might be made that such a system is less distorting than the current hybrid system, but it is not clear that it is more likely to achieve policy goals than other reforms, including not only a movement toward worldwide taxation by ending deferral but also proposals to provide a minimum tax and restrict deductions for costs associated with deferred income or restrict deferral and foreign tax credits for tax havens.\nA House tax proposal, called the \u201cBetter Way\u201d tax plan, would not only move to a territorial tax but convert the income tax into a consumption tax. In this case, equity capital would likely be attracted to the United States from foreign countries because of the elimination, in most respects, of a tax on capital income of firms in the United States.", "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORTS", "active": true, "formats": [ { "format": "HTML", "encoding": "utf-8", "url": "https://www.crs.gov/Reports/RL34115", "sha1": "f23e5ae51a6a084434dca2b5dc2c8880bb9a0924", "filename": "files/20170801_RL34115_f23e5ae51a6a084434dca2b5dc2c8880bb9a0924.html", "images": {} }, { "format": "PDF", "encoding": null, "url": "https://www.crs.gov/Reports/pdf/RL34115", "sha1": "178ea34f550e9a5444e22a86cdfb715d6681ad0b", "filename": "files/20170801_RL34115_178ea34f550e9a5444e22a86cdfb715d6681ad0b.pdf", "images": {} } ], "topics": [ { "source": "IBCList", "id": 4784, "name": "International Law" }, { "source": "IBCList", "id": 4804, "name": "Business & Corporate Taxation" }, { "source": "IBCList", "id": 4825, "name": "International Tax" }, { "source": "IBCList", "id": 4945, "name": "Tax Reform" } ] }, { "source": "EveryCRSReport.com", "id": 442747, "date": "2015-06-03", "retrieved": "2016-04-06T18:58:55.213311", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": "A striking feature of the modern U.S. economy is its growing openness\u2014its increased integration with the rest of the world. The attention of tax policymakers has recently been focused on the growing participation of U.S. firms in the international economy and the increased pressure that engagement places on the U.S. system for taxing overseas business. Is the current U.S. system for taxing U.S. international business the appropriate one for the modern era of globalized business operations, or should its basic structure be reformed?\nThe current U.S. system for taxing international business is a hybrid. In part, the system is based on a residence principle, applying U.S. taxes on a worldwide basis to U.S. firms while granting foreign tax credits to alleviate double taxation. The system, however, also permits U.S. firms to defer foreign-source income indefinitely\u2014a feature that approaches a territorial tax jurisdiction. In keeping with its mixed structure, the system produces a patchwork of economic effects that depend on the location of foreign investment and the circumstances of the firm. Broadly, the system poses a tax incentive to invest in countries with low tax rates of their own and a disincentive to invest in high-tax countries. In theory, U.S. investment should be skewed toward low-tax countries and away from high-tax locations.\nEvaluations of the current tax system vary, and so do prescriptions for reform. According to traditional economic analysis, world economic welfare is maximized by a system that applies the same tax burden to prospective (marginal) foreign and domestic investment so that taxes do not distort investment decisions. Such a system possesses capital export neutrality, and could be accomplished by worldwide taxation applied to all foreign operations along with an unlimited foreign tax credit. In contrast, a system that maximizes national welfare\u2014a system possessing national neutrality\u2014would impose a higher tax burden on foreign investment, thus permitting an overall disincentive for foreign investment. Such a system would impose worldwide taxation but would permit only a deduction, and not a credit, for foreign taxes.\nA tax system based on territorial taxation would exempt overseas business investment from U.S. tax. In recent years, several proponents of territorial taxation have argued that changes in the world economy have rendered traditional prescriptions for international taxation obsolete and instead prescribe territorial taxation as a means of maximizing both world and national economic welfare. For such a system to be neutral, however, capital would have to be completely immobile across locations. A case might be made that such a system is less distorting than the current hybrid system, but it is not clear that it is more likely to achieve policy goals than other reforms, including not only a movement toward worldwide taxation by ending deferral but also proposals to provide a minimum tax and restrict deductions for costs associated with deferred income or restrict deferral and foreign tax credits for tax havens.", "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORTS", "active": true, "formats": [ { "format": "HTML", "encoding": "utf-8", "url": "http://www.crs.gov/Reports/RL34115", "sha1": "32d0ae36c9d4993c10595702b9cc55bdd17819f5", "filename": "files/20150603_RL34115_32d0ae36c9d4993c10595702b9cc55bdd17819f5.html", "images": null }, { "format": "PDF", "encoding": null, "url": "http://www.crs.gov/Reports/pdf/RL34115", "sha1": "515e68ef6f6ef919a71e6121ae25a9d7650e353a", "filename": "files/20150603_RL34115_515e68ef6f6ef919a71e6121ae25a9d7650e353a.pdf", "images": null } ], "topics": [ { "source": "IBCList", "id": 3919, "name": "International Law and U.S. Sovereignty" }, { "source": "IBCList", "id": 4092, "name": "Tax Reform" }, { "source": "IBCList", "id": 571, "name": "Business Taxation" } ] }, { "source": "University of North Texas Libraries Government Documents Department", "sourceLink": "https://digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metadc821858/", "id": "RL34115_2014Dec01", "date": "2014-12-01", "retrieved": "2016-03-19T13:57:26", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": null, "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORT", "active": false, "formats": [ { "format": "PDF", "filename": "files/20141201_RL34115_8e9fdad3071340e920b83d5d5538cabac8e1ec54.pdf" }, { "format": "HTML", "filename": "files/20141201_RL34115_8e9fdad3071340e920b83d5d5538cabac8e1ec54.html" } ], "topics": [] }, { "source": "University of North Texas Libraries Government Documents Department", "sourceLink": "https://digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metadc813042/", "id": "RL34115_2012Dec27", "date": "2012-12-27", "retrieved": "2016-03-19T13:57:26", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": null, "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORT", "active": false, "formats": [ { "format": "PDF", "filename": "files/20121227_RL34115_374ed171ce6b94242c0467606584e7682d0f0ac6.pdf" }, { "format": "HTML", "filename": "files/20121227_RL34115_374ed171ce6b94242c0467606584e7682d0f0ac6.html" } ], "topics": [] }, { "source": "University of North Texas Libraries Government Documents Department", "sourceLink": "https://digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metadc31427/", "id": "RL34115_2010Dec17", "date": "2010-12-17", "retrieved": "2011-03-09T09:26:47", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": "This report describes and assesses the principal prescriptions that have been offered for broad reform of the current U.S. system for taxing international businesses. The report begins with an overview of current law and of possible revisions. It then sets the framework for considering economic efficiency as well as tax shelter activities. Finally, it reviews alternative approaches to revision in light of those issues.", "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORT", "active": false, "formats": [ { "format": "PDF", "filename": "files/20101217_RL34115_f16ae0f461778be990cf7220811765c58ae1f7ec.pdf" }, { "format": "HTML", "filename": "files/20101217_RL34115_f16ae0f461778be990cf7220811765c58ae1f7ec.html" } ], "topics": [ { "source": "LIV", "id": "Taxation", "name": "Taxation" }, { "source": "LIV", "id": "International trade", "name": "International trade" }, { "source": "LIV", "id": "Trade", "name": "Trade" }, { "source": "LIV", "id": "Tax havens", "name": "Tax havens" } ] }, { "source": "University of North Texas Libraries Government Documents Department", "sourceLink": "https://digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metadc818801/", "id": "RL34115_2008Jun09", "date": "2008-06-09", "retrieved": "2016-03-19T13:57:26", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": null, "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORT", "active": false, "formats": [ { "format": "PDF", "filename": "files/20080609_RL34115_a252e2766e114ba04d4d56bd65497fc6862f9cac.pdf" }, { "format": "HTML", "filename": "files/20080609_RL34115_a252e2766e114ba04d4d56bd65497fc6862f9cac.html" } ], "topics": [] }, { "source": "University of North Texas Libraries Government Documents Department", "sourceLink": "https://digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metadc822025/", "id": "RL34115_2007Jul31", "date": "2007-07-31", "retrieved": "2016-03-19T13:57:26", "title": "Reform of U.S. International Taxation: Alternatives", "summary": null, "type": "CRS Report", "typeId": "REPORT", "active": false, "formats": [ { "format": "PDF", "filename": "files/20070731_RL34115_24ba5437f0e2128ef923b419f658d1ea44eb5000.pdf" }, { "format": "HTML", "filename": "files/20070731_RL34115_24ba5437f0e2128ef923b419f658d1ea44eb5000.html" } ], "topics": [] } ], "topics": [ "Economic Policy" ] }